“Global Economic Shocks and Indian Policy Response: An Analysis Using a CGE Model”

 

Citation: Ganesh-Kumar, A. and M. Panda. 2009. “Global Economic Shocks and Indian Policy Response: An Analysis Using a CGE model”. In K. S. Parikh (Ed.) Macro-Modeling for the Eleventh Five Year Plan of India, Planning Commission, Government of India / Academic Foundation, New Delhi.

 

Executive summary

 

1)    The year 2008 has been a tumultuous one in the history of the world economy unparalleled in several decades. The first half of 2008 witnessed dramatic rise in the global prices of crude oil and petroleum products. During the second half of 2008, the global economy slipped into a recession triggered by the financial meltdown in the developed economies that invoked comparisons with the Great Depression of the 1930s. Along side commodity prices too fell sharply. The fallout of these developments in the world economy is already being felt in India in several ways. Exports have virtually stagnated, while capital inflows have fallen and even reversed at times. These shocks emanating from the world economy have posed particular challenges to the Indian policy makers. The question in the first half of 2008 was how to contain the effects of global oil price rise, while in the second half of 2008 policy attention has shifted to designing effective counter measures to limit the adverse effects of the global recession. Against this background, this study analyses the likely impacts of these global shocks on the Indian economy and different sections of the society.

Analytical framework

2)    In order to study these issues we have developed a basic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of the Indian economy in an open economy framework with 71 sectors and 10 household classes. It is built around the social accounting matrix (SAM) of 2003-04. In each tradable sector domestic goods and foreign goods are treated as imperfect substitutes of each other following the Armington specification. Along with imperfect substitutability, indirect taxes and tariffs permit multiple price layers for each sector. Income distribution across households depends upon the endogenous levels of (un)employment of both labour and capital. The model determines relative prices but does not, however, have money as a store of value. It is a static one, particularly suitable for assessing short-run growth and distributional impacts.

3)    Two sets of simulations are carried out in this study to assess the impact on the Indian economy of (I) global oil price rise and the policy options for India, and (II) global recession and the effectiveness of some of the government’s counter measures including expansion of the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS). Towards this the basic CGE model is suitably extended to incorporate additional features such as (a) administered pricing mechanism as exists in the petroleum products sector in India, and (b) incorporation of the working of the NREGS along with segmented labour markets. The modeling of the NREGS captures the guarantee element of the Programme by linking its size (i.e., number of jobs generated and the cost to the government) to the endogenous levels of unemployment of rural labour. To the best of our knowledge, this is perhaps the first ever attempt at modeling the NREGS.

Global Oil Price Rise and Policy Options for India

4)    The first set of simulations evaluates the impacts of a 70% rise in crude oil prices and 50% rise in petroleum products prices (a) when the domestic prices of petroleum products are administratively kept unchanged by the government, (b) when the government administratively raises the price of petroleum products by 10%, and (c) when administered pricing mechanism is replaced with market determined pricing for petroleum products.

5)    The main results of these simulations are the following:

a)    In the short-run, GDP falls by about half a percentage point over the base levels and real exchange rate depreciates by about 20%, due to international price rise in crude oil and petroleum products sector, irrespective of the pricing mechanism prevailing in the domestic petroleum products sector.

b)    The rise in world prices results in a 1% rise in aggregate domestic price index even when the government keeps the domestic price of petroleum products unchanged. Domestic prices rise by 1.9% following a 10% hike in the administered price of petroleum products, and by 4.7% when the administered pricing mechanism is replaced with market determined pricing system.

c)    Under a market determined price regime global oil price rise unambiguously hurts all households across both rural and urban areas, with the urban households in each class suffering a greater loss in real incomes than their counterparts in rural areas. Administered pricing benefits or mutes the real income losses for most households.

d)    Government’s subsidy bill due to administered pricing works out to Rs.851 billions when the price of petroleum products is left unchanged at the base level. The subsidy bill reduces by Rs.316 billions following a 10% hike in the administered price. In contrast under market determined prices, government get a larger tax revenue compared to the base.

e)    Under administered pricing, the subsidy provided to the petroleum products sector benefits the producers also in the form of higher net- / value-added price, which rise by nearly 50% when the prices are not changed compared to a 70% decline in the net-price under market determined pricing system. In other words, market determined prices forces the producers to absorb part of the global price rise.

f)      The rise in government subsidy for petroleum products has adverse effects on the government’s savings, and hence national savings and investment. Government’s dis-savings nearly doubles when the administered price is kept unchanged, while a 10% hike in the price reduces the government’s dis-savings by 25%. In contrast, government dis-savings rise by just 13% under free market regime compared to base.

g)    The main cost of global oil price rise is the fall in real investments, by 14.3% under no change in administered price, by 11.5% after a 10% hike in administered prices, and by 5.1% when the pricing in the petroleum products sector is market determined. 

Global Economic Recession: Impacts and Counter Measures

6)    The second set of simulations examine the effects of three external developments: (i) a 10% fall in Indian exports due to falling external demand, (ii) a 29% reduction in the foreign inflows into India comprising of 10% fall in remittances and 15% fall in foreign savings, and (iii) a 10% fall in global oil prices which is passed through to consumers. We have then attempted to analyze how much of the adverse impact on Indian economy could be offset by three government policies: (i) 5% increase in government consumption, (ii) 2% cut in indirect tax rate, and (iii) expansion of the rural employment guarantee scheme to ensure base level of living for the bottom 70% of the rural population.

7)    The results from these simulations show that,

a)    Of the three external developments, exports fall alone results in a loss in GDP by about 3.3%, while fall in capital inflows cause another 1.8% loss in GDP. The fall in international crude prices mutes the GDP loss somewhat. Nevertheless the combined effect of the external shocks potentially could be a loss in GDP of about 4.2%.

b)    About half of this combined effect could be offset by government counter measures examined here and overall adverse effect on GDP could be limited to fall by 2.2%.

c)    Assuming a growth rate of 9% for 2008-09 as per the XI Plan target under normal circumstances, the external shocks together could reduce the growth rate to as low as 3.9%, but the counter measures could help lift it up to 6.8%.

d)    While the loss in growth could be arrested somewhat in the short-run through these counter-measures, it could be at the cost of long-term growth and fiscal erosion. The results show that all these global developments and the counter measures would lead to decline in real investment by 20.7% and near doubling of government dis-savings.

e)    Manufacturing sector suffers relatively more loss in output than agriculture or services sector in all the scenarios. In fact, two of the counter measures, viz., rise in government consumption and reduction in indirect taxes actually hurt the manufacturing sector because of the fall in investment demand in these scenarios.

f)      About 4.3% of the total labour force could suffer unemployment following the three external shocks. Rising government consumption and cutting down indirect taxes could limit the unemployment to just 2.7%. Expanding the NREGS to fully cover the bottom 70% of the rural population could bring down the unemployment by an additional 0.5% through its direct and indirect effects.

g)    Real income losses for households following the external shocks range between 3.6% and 4.5%, with the urban households suffering slightly higher losses than their rural counterparts.

h)    An expanded NREGS can actually help in rising the real incomes of the bottom 70% of the rural population over the base levels even under these recessionary conditions. And it would cost about Rs.331 billions or about 1.4% of the nominal GDP.

8)    It is worth reiterating at the end that CGE models are real models that consider only relative price movements. The absence of money market in the model limits us from examining the impact of several monetary measures adopted by government of India to counter the external shocks.