“Policy Options
for 9% Growth during the Twelfth Five Year Plan of India: Some Results Using a
CGE Model”
Citation: Ganesh-Kumar, A. and M. Panda. 2011.
“Policy Options for 9% Growth during the Twelfth Five Year Plan of India: Some
Results Using a CGE Model”. Report submitted to the Planning Commission, New
Delhi.
Abstract:
In this
paper, we explore some policy options corresponding to a high 9% growth in
Indian economy during the Twelfth Five Year Plan. We use a modified and updated
version of a CGE model calibrated for a base solution around a new social
accounting matrix for 2006-07 and solved sequentially over time for a ten-year
period covering the 11th and 12th Plan periods. Several alternative policy
scenarios have been developed around a base as usual (BAU) scenario by
considering shifting of resources towards agriculture and industry and towards
distributional programmes like the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme.
The BAU
scenario for 12th Plan incorporates the expected pattern of growth across the
broad sectors based on recent experience with an average growth rate of 3.7%,
9.5% and 10.0% in agriculture, industry and services respectively.
Correspondingly, the structure of the economy would change substantially during
the 11th and 12th Plans. The share of agriculture in GDP falls from 14.6% in
2011-12 to 11.4% in 2016-17 with corresponding rise in share of service from
57.6% in 2011-12 to 60.2% in 2016-17. Savings and investment rates are expected
to reach 40% of GDP by the end of the 12th Plan. The average income of various
classes rises by 1.8% to 6.9% per annum in real terms. But, higher income
classes gain more than those at the bottom end implying more adverse income
distribution.
Two
alternative scenarios, ‘pro-agriculture’ and ‘pro-industry’ are designed to
tilt the sectoral growth pattern towards agriculture and industry even while
maintaining an overall growth in GDP at about 9%. An additional agricultural
growth of 1.2% over the BAU could lead to a fall in relative price of
agriculture by 3.1% with favourable effects on real wages and private consumption.
The adverse income distribution in the BAU gets moderated because the poorer
sections gain more in real terms due to fall in agricultural prices.
An additional
industrial growth of 1% in the pro-industry scenario leads to fall in relative
price of industry by 1.2% while that of services rise by 1.4%. All income classes witness loss in real
income, the maximum being 1% for urban top most decile. Income distribution
improves because the loss for the upper income classes is relatively larger
compared to that for the lower income groups.
The NREGS
scenarios are implemented by expanding the exogenously given labour endowments
of the bottom 70% of rural population by 3%. GDP effect of introduction of
NREGS of this scale is negligible without productivity effect, but composition
of GDP moves marginally in favour agriculture. Aggregate private consumption
rises by 0.3% compared to corresponding scenarios without NREGS. The upward
pressure on agricultural prices is not large; it is about 0.3% over BAU. NREGS has
large distributional implications. The per capita income of bottom 70% of rural
population rises by 1.3 to 1.8% in the terminal year over the BAU; but, all
urban classes lose marginally due to the relative price effect.