“Growth and
Welfare Consequences of a Rise in Minimum Support Prices: An Applied General
Equilibrium Analysis for
Citation: Parikh, K. S., A. Ganesh-Kumar and
G. Darbha. 2002. “Growth and Welfare Consequences of
a Rise in Minimum Support Prices: An Applied General Equilibrium Analysis for
India”. Report of the project “Minimum
Support Price for Food Grains and its Implications for Food Security of the
Poor”, submitted to the Department of Economic Affairs, Ministry of
Finance, Government of India, New Delhi.
Executive
Summary:
1.
Introduction
1.
The
mounting food stocks amidst substantial poverty and under nutrition raise
questions on our agricultural policy. Government food stocks were 59.1 million
tonnes as of
2.
The
main reason for increase in food stocks is related to the government
procurement price policy. The problem is the level at which the government sets
procurement prices, which have become minimum support prices (MSP) over the
years. These prices for many years now have been higher than what free market
prices would have been. The government, through Food Corporation of India (FCI)
buys up whatever is offered at procurement prices ensuring that the harvest
price for a particular commodity does not fall below its procurement price.
Under the pressure of the farm lobby the prices are set high. At these prices,
what farmers produce consumers do not demand for want of adequate purchasing
power.
3.
The
procurement prices are set by the government on the recommendation of committee
on agricultural costs and prices (CACP). The CACP’s recommendations are based
on costs of cultivation and adequate return to farmers. For a number of recent
years, the government has set prices particularly of wheat, at higher levels
than recommended by the CACP.
4.
What
happens when government increases procurement prices? High procurement price
gives farmers incentive to produce more. They will use more fertilizers and
increase yield. Higher price would reduce demand. To support price FCI would
have to procure more. Stocks would rise further. Government will have to
finance the addition to stock. This is done by cutting some other expenditure.
The easiest to cut is investment. Less would be invested in agriculture.
Irrigation capacity would not grow as much. In a year or two the cumulative
impact of lower irrigation would reduce growth rate of agricultural output
despite higher procurement price. Farmers themselves could be worse off
compared to what they could have been had investment in irrigation not reduced.
5.
Apart
from that consumers and particularly the poor consumers may also be hurt. The
poor consisting of landless labour, small and marginal farmers are net
purchasers of food. They are able to buy less food even when one accounts for
increase in wage rate that may follow higher procurement price.
6.
In
order to appreciate better the consequences of a procurement price hike, it
would be instructive to analyze the exact
quantitative impact of a price hike on the growth and welfare of producers and
consumers. To undertake such an exercise in a credible way, we need a numerical
simulation model that accounts for the inter-sectoral interactions that one
finds in a modern economy, price determination and income distribution
mechanisms. This study explores in an integrated way the consequences of
increasing MSP of wheat and rice by 10 per cent.
2. An
applied general equilibrium model of
7.
For
this purpose we built a dynamic Applied General Equilibrium model for
8.
This
model used in this study is characterised by 65 commodity producing sectors 10
types of households classified first by their location of residence into two
broad groups – RURAL and URBAN and within each of them into 5 classes based on
their annual per capita real expenditure. The model is sequentially dynamic in
the sense that it is solved for every year in a sequential manner with the
previous year’s solution providing a starting value for the next year. The
policy shock that we analyze is a one
time 10% hike in procurement price of Wheat and Rice.
3. The
scenarios
9.
Policy
analysis using a model requires specification of the prevailing and changed
policy regimes. To facilitate comparison a base / reference scenario is first
generated and the outcomes of policy scenarios are compared with that of
reference scenario.
10. The reference scenario, labelled
“REF”, against which policy scenarios are compared is a business-as-usual
scenario in which the policy environment specified in the model corresponds to
the actual policies observed during the base period, 1996-97. The policy
scenario is designed as a one time increase by 10% in
the support price of these two commodities in the second year, with all other
parameters kept at their base scenario levels. That is, the government assures
the producers of rice and wheat a 10% higher price by committing to buy
whatever amounts of these two commodities that they may offer for sale. Given
fixed rates of trade and transport margins and indirect tax / subsidies on
these two commodities, this hike in procurement price and hence producer price
will translate into a commensurate rise in both their market price and the
ration price.
4. Results
4.1 Macro
impacts
11. A hike in procurement prices of rice
and wheat results in a marginal decline in total GDP (at constant prices) in
the first year of the price hike, because of a fall in GDP non-agriculture.
Agricultural GDP is marginally higher. This increase in agricultural GDP is,
however, insufficient to compensate for the fall in non-agricultural GDP and
consequently, total GDP is lower in in all the years.
12. The fall in non-agricultural GDP is
attributable to the decline in aggregate demand due to rise in the overall
price indices and decline in total fixed investments in the economy. The rise
in overall price indices to the tune of 1 to 1.5 percent leads to a general
reduction in real incomes and hence demand. Non-agricultural output being
demand determined consequently declines. The decline in fixed investments is
due to the additional expenditure that the government incurs to support the
hike in procurement prices. This additional expenditure arises due to both an
increase in procurement prices as well as the quantity procured. Given the
overall resource constraint, the additional expenditure on building up stocks
comes at the cost of a decline in fixed investments. While the additional
expenditure on stocks favours only rice and wheat, the decline in fixed
investments adversely affects the demand for many non-agricultural sectors, and
hence the decline in non-agricultural GDP.
13. The results in decline in overall
investments decline in agricultural investment also despite the higher relative
price of agriculture and in the later years is felt in terms of virtually
insignificant growth in gross irrigated area and gross cropped area, and hence
agricultural GDP, despite a favourable shift in relative prices towards
agriculture.
14. Thus from a macro perspective, the
results indicate that the policy to hike procurement prices of rice and wheat
has an adverse impact on overall growth, raises the level of inflation, reduces
investment, and has a miniscule impact on agricultural GDP.
4.2 Impact
on Agricultural Production, Consumption and Stocks
15. With the hike in prices of rice and
wheat, the output of these sectors increase by 1.6 and 2.6 percent,
respectively, only in the year immediately following the price hike. This
increase in output is not sustained over time because of the fall in
agricultural investments and irrigated area seen earlier. The hike in procurement
prices results in increase in all prices, producer, ration as well as consumer
prices, as explained earlier. This in turn, leads to a significant decline in
total private consumption of these two commodities by around 3 to 3.5 percent.
Indeed self-consumption of both these commodities is higher the ration and the
market consumption are lower in response to increase in prices. The increase in
output along with a decline in consumption results in a build
up of stocks of these two commodities. For rice, stocks are larger by
12.9, 28.6 and 43.4 percent for the years 1998, 1999 and 2000 respectively
compared to the REF. For wheat these are larger by 11.0, 23.3 and 25.8 percent,
respectively. The combined stocks of rice and wheat at the end of three years
come to around 66.6 million tonnes compared to 50.1 million tonnes in the REF.
The effects of an increase in relative prices of rice and wheat on output,
consumption and stocks of other agricultural commodities are quantitatively
marginal.
4.3
Welfare impacts
16. The cross-sectional impact of the
price hike in terms of distribution of population, income and welfare are
instructive. There is a significant increase in the population in the poorer
classes, both in rural and urban areas. Comparison of the two income
distributions under assumptions of Pareto principle, anonymity and aversion to
regressive transfers, clearly indicate a significant worsening of welfare of 80
percent of population in rural areas and all persons in urban areas with higher
MSPs. Further, the welfare loss is in general larger for urban population than
for rural population across classes and over time. The welfare loss is in
general regressive in the sense that the lower classes seem to lose more than
the upper classes. Only the top 20 percent of the rural population experience
welfare increases in the third year. It should be emphasized that rural
population get part of their income from non-agricultural activities. Thus the
decline in non-agricultural output affects adversely the income of rural
population also, which to some extent neutralizes the gains from increase in
agricultural prices. The top quantile of rural population has a larger
marketable surplus of wheat and rice and they also get a relatively larger
share of non-agricultural income.
17. While the immediate welfare loss due
to a general price hike (procurement, ration and market price) is obvious, the
welfare loss over time can be explained in terms of the decline in overall GDP
attributable to a decline in non-agricultural GDP and mild growth in
agriculture output as the decline in fixed investments almost completely
offsets the incentive effects of higher MSPs.
5.
Conclusions
18. We have seen that a 10 percent
increase in minimum support prices of wheat and rice leads to decline in
overall GDP by 0.33 percent, increase in aggregate price index by 1.5 percent,
reduction in investments by 1.9 percent and a miniscule impact on Agricultural
GDP by the third year. What is more important to note is that in terms of
welfare the bottom 80 percent of the rural and all of urban population is worse
off.
19. The results are easy to understand.
Higher minimum support prices reduce demand and lead to larger stocks. Thus the
stocks of wheat and rice are larger by 16.5 million tonnes after 3 years and
reach 66.5 million tonnes compared to a reference scenario. We have assumed
that a government under hard budget constraints can finance the expenditure on
additional stocks only by reducing its investment expenditure, including investment
in irrigation. We consider this to be a realistic assumption. This leads to
lower agricultural output overtime and even the farmers get hurt.
20. Thus the minimum support prices at
levels much above market clearing prices are not desirable. One should emphasize
here that the adverse impact of increases in MSP is related to the level of MSP
to begin with. Only when the increases push up prices above the market clearing
prices that the problems arise. Thus we
conclude that government should announce minimum support prices that remain
below the market clearing prices in a normal or modal year. In an exceptionally
bumper year the market clearing prices would be lower than the announced MSPs.
This, however, is fine as in such years, the farmers need support which should
be provided.